The magic money tree problemWhy is statistics useful when many things that matter are one shot things?Using the probability generating function to find the probability of ultimate extinctionBasic question about the filtration in the martingale formed by sum of iid random variablesMagic Urn ProblemHow do 'money back if your horse places' bets not lose the bookies' money?ABRACADABRA ProblemPage 227 of The Undoing ProjectProblem Sampling with Metropolis HastingsThe Kelly Criterion — Where Did I Go Wrong?Capital distribution between several bets

is the intersection of subgroups a subgroup of each subgroup

Show that if two triangles built on parallel lines, with equal bases have the same perimeter only if they are congruent.

Is it tax fraud for an individual to declare non-taxable revenue as taxable income? (US tax laws)

Languages that we cannot (dis)prove to be Context-Free

What defenses are there against being summoned by the Gate spell?

Is it unprofessional to ask if a job posting on GlassDoor is real?

Animated Series: Alien black spider robot crashes on Earth

"You are your self first supporter", a more proper way to say it

I’m planning on buying a laser printer but concerned about the life cycle of toner in the machine

Theorems that impeded progress

Mathematical cryptic clues

How to format long polynomial?

What does "Puller Prush Person" mean?

If I cast Expeditious Retreat, can I Dash as a bonus action on the same turn?

The Two and the One

The use of multiple foreign keys on same column in SQL Server

Did Shadowfax go to Valinor?

"to be prejudice towards/against someone" vs "to be prejudiced against/towards someone"

Can I make popcorn with any corn?

Why does Kotter return in Welcome Back Kotter?

Accidentally leaked the solution to an assignment, what to do now? (I'm the prof)

What's the point of deactivating Num Lock on login screens?

Is it important to consider tone, melody, and musical form while writing a song?

What does it mean to describe someone as a butt steak?



The magic money tree problem


Why is statistics useful when many things that matter are one shot things?Using the probability generating function to find the probability of ultimate extinctionBasic question about the filtration in the martingale formed by sum of iid random variablesMagic Urn ProblemHow do 'money back if your horse places' bets not lose the bookies' money?ABRACADABRA ProblemPage 227 of The Undoing ProjectProblem Sampling with Metropolis HastingsThe Kelly Criterion — Where Did I Go Wrong?Capital distribution between several bets






.everyoneloves__top-leaderboard:empty,.everyoneloves__mid-leaderboard:empty,.everyoneloves__bot-mid-leaderboard:empty margin-bottom:0;








6












$begingroup$


I thought of this problem in the shower, it was inspired by investment strategies.



Let's say there was a magic money tree. Every day, you can offer an amount of money to the money tree and it will either triple it, or destroy it with 50/50 probability. You immediately notice that on average you will gain money by doing this and are eager to take advantage of the money tree. However, if you offered all your money at once, you would have a 50% of losing all your money. Unacceptable! You are a pretty risk-averse person, so you decide to come up with a strategy. You want to minimize the odds of losing everything, but you also want to make as much money as you can! You come up with the following: every day, you offer 20% of your current capital to the money tree. Assuming the lowest you can offer is 1 cent, it would take a 31 loss streak to lose all your money if you started with 10 dollars. What's more, the more cash you earn, the longer the losing streak needs to be for you to lose everything, amazing! You quickly start earning loads of cash. But then an idea pops into your head: you can just offer 30% each day and make way more money! But wait, why not offer 35%? 50%? One day, with big dollar signs in your eyes you run up to the money tree with all your millions and offer up 100% of your cash, which the money tree promptly burns. The next day you get a job at McDonalds.



Is there an optimal percentage of your cash you can offer without losing it all?



(sub) questions:



If there is an optimal percentage you should offer, is this static (i.e. 20% every day) or should the percentage grow as your capital increases?



By offering 20% every day, do the odds of losing all your money decrease or increase over time? Is there a percentage of money from where the odds of losing all your money increase over time?










share|cite|improve this question









New contributor




ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
Check out our Code of Conduct.







$endgroup$







  • 3




    $begingroup$
    This seems like a variation on Gambler's ruin
    $endgroup$
    – Robert Long
    21 hours ago

















6












$begingroup$


I thought of this problem in the shower, it was inspired by investment strategies.



Let's say there was a magic money tree. Every day, you can offer an amount of money to the money tree and it will either triple it, or destroy it with 50/50 probability. You immediately notice that on average you will gain money by doing this and are eager to take advantage of the money tree. However, if you offered all your money at once, you would have a 50% of losing all your money. Unacceptable! You are a pretty risk-averse person, so you decide to come up with a strategy. You want to minimize the odds of losing everything, but you also want to make as much money as you can! You come up with the following: every day, you offer 20% of your current capital to the money tree. Assuming the lowest you can offer is 1 cent, it would take a 31 loss streak to lose all your money if you started with 10 dollars. What's more, the more cash you earn, the longer the losing streak needs to be for you to lose everything, amazing! You quickly start earning loads of cash. But then an idea pops into your head: you can just offer 30% each day and make way more money! But wait, why not offer 35%? 50%? One day, with big dollar signs in your eyes you run up to the money tree with all your millions and offer up 100% of your cash, which the money tree promptly burns. The next day you get a job at McDonalds.



Is there an optimal percentage of your cash you can offer without losing it all?



(sub) questions:



If there is an optimal percentage you should offer, is this static (i.e. 20% every day) or should the percentage grow as your capital increases?



By offering 20% every day, do the odds of losing all your money decrease or increase over time? Is there a percentage of money from where the odds of losing all your money increase over time?










share|cite|improve this question









New contributor




ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
Check out our Code of Conduct.







$endgroup$







  • 3




    $begingroup$
    This seems like a variation on Gambler's ruin
    $endgroup$
    – Robert Long
    21 hours ago













6












6








6





$begingroup$


I thought of this problem in the shower, it was inspired by investment strategies.



Let's say there was a magic money tree. Every day, you can offer an amount of money to the money tree and it will either triple it, or destroy it with 50/50 probability. You immediately notice that on average you will gain money by doing this and are eager to take advantage of the money tree. However, if you offered all your money at once, you would have a 50% of losing all your money. Unacceptable! You are a pretty risk-averse person, so you decide to come up with a strategy. You want to minimize the odds of losing everything, but you also want to make as much money as you can! You come up with the following: every day, you offer 20% of your current capital to the money tree. Assuming the lowest you can offer is 1 cent, it would take a 31 loss streak to lose all your money if you started with 10 dollars. What's more, the more cash you earn, the longer the losing streak needs to be for you to lose everything, amazing! You quickly start earning loads of cash. But then an idea pops into your head: you can just offer 30% each day and make way more money! But wait, why not offer 35%? 50%? One day, with big dollar signs in your eyes you run up to the money tree with all your millions and offer up 100% of your cash, which the money tree promptly burns. The next day you get a job at McDonalds.



Is there an optimal percentage of your cash you can offer without losing it all?



(sub) questions:



If there is an optimal percentage you should offer, is this static (i.e. 20% every day) or should the percentage grow as your capital increases?



By offering 20% every day, do the odds of losing all your money decrease or increase over time? Is there a percentage of money from where the odds of losing all your money increase over time?










share|cite|improve this question









New contributor




ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
Check out our Code of Conduct.







$endgroup$




I thought of this problem in the shower, it was inspired by investment strategies.



Let's say there was a magic money tree. Every day, you can offer an amount of money to the money tree and it will either triple it, or destroy it with 50/50 probability. You immediately notice that on average you will gain money by doing this and are eager to take advantage of the money tree. However, if you offered all your money at once, you would have a 50% of losing all your money. Unacceptable! You are a pretty risk-averse person, so you decide to come up with a strategy. You want to minimize the odds of losing everything, but you also want to make as much money as you can! You come up with the following: every day, you offer 20% of your current capital to the money tree. Assuming the lowest you can offer is 1 cent, it would take a 31 loss streak to lose all your money if you started with 10 dollars. What's more, the more cash you earn, the longer the losing streak needs to be for you to lose everything, amazing! You quickly start earning loads of cash. But then an idea pops into your head: you can just offer 30% each day and make way more money! But wait, why not offer 35%? 50%? One day, with big dollar signs in your eyes you run up to the money tree with all your millions and offer up 100% of your cash, which the money tree promptly burns. The next day you get a job at McDonalds.



Is there an optimal percentage of your cash you can offer without losing it all?



(sub) questions:



If there is an optimal percentage you should offer, is this static (i.e. 20% every day) or should the percentage grow as your capital increases?



By offering 20% every day, do the odds of losing all your money decrease or increase over time? Is there a percentage of money from where the odds of losing all your money increase over time?







probability mathematical-statistics econometrics random-walk martingale






share|cite|improve this question









New contributor




ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
Check out our Code of Conduct.











share|cite|improve this question









New contributor




ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
Check out our Code of Conduct.









share|cite|improve this question




share|cite|improve this question








edited 8 hours ago









Martijn Weterings

14.9k1964




14.9k1964






New contributor




ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
Check out our Code of Conduct.









asked 21 hours ago









ElectronicToothpickElectronicToothpick

1311




1311




New contributor




ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
Check out our Code of Conduct.





New contributor





ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
Check out our Code of Conduct.






ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
Check out our Code of Conduct.







  • 3




    $begingroup$
    This seems like a variation on Gambler's ruin
    $endgroup$
    – Robert Long
    21 hours ago












  • 3




    $begingroup$
    This seems like a variation on Gambler's ruin
    $endgroup$
    – Robert Long
    21 hours ago







3




3




$begingroup$
This seems like a variation on Gambler's ruin
$endgroup$
– Robert Long
21 hours ago




$begingroup$
This seems like a variation on Gambler's ruin
$endgroup$
– Robert Long
21 hours ago










4 Answers
4






active

oldest

votes


















3












$begingroup$

This is a well-known problem. It is called a Kelly bet. The answer, by the way, is 1/3rd. It is equivalent to maximizing the log utility of wealth.



Kelly began with taking time to infinity and then solving backward. Since you can always express returns in terms of continuous compounding, then you can also reverse the process and express it in logs. I am going to use the log utility explanation, but the log utility is a convenience. If you are maximizing wealth as $ntoinfty$ then you will end up with a function that works out to be the same as log utility. If $b$ is the payout odds, and $p$ is the probability of winning, and $X$ is the percentage of wealth invested, then the following derivation will work.



For a binary bet, $E(log(X))=plog(1+bX)+(1-p)log(1-X)$, for a single period and unit wealth.



$$fracddXE[log(x)]=fracddX[plog(1+bX)+(1-p)log(1-X)]$$
$$=fracpb1+bX-frac1-p1-X$$



Setting the derivative to zero to find the extrema,



$$fracpb1+bX-frac1-p1-X=0$$



Cross multiplying, you end up with $$pb(1-X)-(1-p)(1+bX)=0$$
$$pb-pbX-1-bX+p+pbX=0$$
$$bX=pb-1+p$$
$$X=fracbp-(1-p)b$$



In your case, $$X=frac3timesfrac12-(1-frac12)3=frac13.$$



You can readily expand this to multiple or continuous outcomes by solving the expected utility of wealth over a joint probability distribution, choosing the allocations and subject to any constraints. Interestingly, if you perform it in this manner, by including constraints, such as the ability to meet mortgage payments and so forth, then you have accounted for your total set of risks and so you have a risk-adjusted or at least risk-controlled solution.



Desiderata The actual purpose of the original research had to do with how much to gamble based on a noisy signal. In the specific case, how much to gamble on a noisy electronic signal where it indicated the launch of nuclear weapons by the Soviet Union. There have been several near launches by both the United States and Russia, obviously in error. How much do you gamble on a signal?






share|cite|improve this answer









$endgroup$












  • $begingroup$
    This strategy would give a higher risk of going broke I think compared to lower fractions
    $endgroup$
    – probabilityislogic
    3 hours ago










  • $begingroup$
    @probabilityislogic Only in the case where pennies exist. In the discrete case, it would become true because you could bet your last penny. You couldn't bet a third of a penny. In a discrete world, it is intrinsically true that the probability of bankruptcy must be increasing in allocation size, independent of the payoff case. A 2% allocation has a greater probability of bankruptcy than a 1% in a discrete world.
    $endgroup$
    – Dave Harris
    2 hours ago










  • $begingroup$
    @probabilityislogic if you begin with 3 cents then it is risky. If you start with $550 then there is less than one chance in 1024 of going bankrupt. For reasonable pot sizes, the risk of discrete collapse becomes small unless you really go to infinity, then it becomes a certainty unless borrowing is allowed.
    $endgroup$
    – Dave Harris
    2 hours ago



















2












$begingroup$

I don't think this is much different from the Martingale. In your case, there are no doubling bets, but the winning payout is 3x.



I coded a "replica" of your tree. I run 10 simulations. In each simulation (trace), you start with 200 coins and try with the tree, 1 coin each time for 20000 times.



The only conditions that stop the simulation are bankruptcy or having "survived" 20k attempts



enter image description here



So long as the winning odds are 50% or less, sooner or later bankruptcy awaits you.






share|cite|improve this answer








New contributor




Carles Alcolea is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
Check out our Code of Conduct.






$endgroup$












  • $begingroup$
    Are you able to post the code that you wrote for this as well please?
    $endgroup$
    – baxx
    10 hours ago


















1












$begingroup$



Problem statement



Let $Y_t = log_10(M_t)$ be the logarithm of the amount of money $M_t$ the gambler has at time $t$.



  • The gambler starts with $$Y_0 = S = 1$$.


  • The gambler goes banckrupt whenever $$Y_t< L = -2$$.


Simplification.



  • The gambler stops gambling when he has passed some amount of money $$Y_t > W = 7$$

Random walk



Let $b$ be the fraction of money that you are betting. You can see the growth and decline of the money as an asymmetric random walk. That is you can describe $Y_t$ as:



$$Y_t = Y_0 + sum_i=1^t X_i$$



where



$$mathbbP[X_i= a_w =log(1+2b)] = mathbbP[X_i= a_l =log(1-b)] = frac12$$



Martingale



The expression



$$Z_t = c^Y_t$$



is a martingale when we choose $c$ such that.



$$c^a_w+ c^a_l = 2$$ (where $c<1$ if $b<0.5$). Since in that case



$$E[Z_t+1] = E[Z_t] frac12 c^a_w + E[Z_t] frac12 c^a_l = E[Z_t]$$



Probability to end up bankrupt



The stopping time (bankrupty $Y_t < L$ or winning $Y_t>W$) is almost surely finite, since it requires in the worst case a winning streak (or loosing streak) of a certain finite length, $fracW-Sa_w$, which is almost surely gonna happen.



Then, we can use the optional stopping theorem to say $E[Z_tau]$ at the stopping time $tau$ equals the expected value $E[Z_0]$ at time zero.



Thus



$$c^S = E[Z_0] = E[Z_tau] approx mathbbP[Y_tau<L] c^L + (1-mathbbP[Y_tau<L]) c^W$$



and



$$ mathbbP[Y_tau<L] approx fracc^S-c^Wc^L-c^W$$



and the limit $W to infty$



$$ mathbbP[Y_tau<L] approx c^S-L$$



Conclusion



When the gambler bets less than half the money (such that $c<1$) then the gambler will not certainly go bankrupt, and the probability to end up bankrupt will be less when the gambler is betting with a smaller fraction.



Simulations



simulations



# functions to compute c
cx = function(c,x)
c^log(1-x,10)+c^log(1+2*x,10) - 2

findc = function(x)
r <- uniroot(cx, c(0,1-0.1^10),x=x,tol=10^-130)
r$root



# settings
set.seed(1)
n <- 100000
n2 <- 1000
b <- 0.45

# repeating different betting strategies
for (b in c(0.35,0.4,0.45))
# plot empty canvas
plot(1,-1000,
xlim=c(0,n2),ylim=c(-2,50),
type="l",
xlab = "time step", ylab = expression(log[10](M[t])) )

# steps in the logarithm of the money
steps <- c(log(1+2*b,10),log(1-b,10))

# counter for number of bankrupts
bank <- 0

# computing 1000 times
for (i in 1:1000)
# sampling wins or looses
X_t <- sample(steps, n, replace = TRUE)
# compute log of money
Y_t <- 1+cumsum(X_t)
# compute money
M_t <- 10^Y_t
# optional stopping (bankruptcy)
tau <- min(c(n,which(-2 > Y_t)))
if (tau<n)
bank <- bank+1

# plot only 100 to prevent clutter
if (i<=100)
col=rgb(tau<n,0,0,0.5)
lines(1:tau,Y_t[1:tau],col=col)


text(0,45,paste0(bank, " bankruptcies out of 1000 n", "theoretic bankruptcy rate is ", round(findc(b)^3,4)),cex=1,pos=4)
title(paste0("betting a fraction ", round(b,2)))






share|cite|improve this answer











$endgroup$




















    1












    $begingroup$

    I liked the answer given by Dave harris. just though I would come at the problem from a "low risk" perspective, rather than profit maximising



    The random walk you are doing, assuming your fraction bet is $q$ and probability of winning $p=0.5$ has is given as
    $$Y_t|Y_t-1=(1-q+3qX_t)Y_t-1$$
    where $X_tsim Bernoulli(p)$. on average you have
    $$E(Y_t|Y_t-1) = (1-q+3pq)Y_t-1$$
    You can iteratively apply this to get
    $$Y_t|Y_0=Y_0prod_j=1^t (1-q+3qX_t)$$
    with expected value
    $$E(Y_t|Y_0) = (1-q+3pq)^t Y_0$$
    you can also express the amount at time $t$ as a function of a single random variable $Z_t=sum_j=1^t X_tsim Binomial(t,p)$, but noting that $Z_t$ is not independent from $Z_t-1$
    $$Y_t|Y_0=Y_0 (1+2q)^Z_t(1-q)^t-Z_t$$



    possible strategy



    you could use this formula to determine a "low risk" value for $q$. Say assuming you wanted to ensure that after $k$ consecutive losses you still had half your original wealth. Then you set $q=1-2^-k^-1$



    Taking the example $k=5$ means we set $q=0.129$, or with $k=15$ we set $q=0.045$.



    Also, due to the recursive nature of the strategy, this risk is what you are taking every at every single bet. That is, at time $s$, by continuing to play you are ensuring that at time $k+s$ your wealth will be at least $0.5Y_s$



    discussion



    the above strategy does not depend on the pay off from winning, but rather about setting a boundary on losing. We can get the expected winnings by substituting in the value for $q$ we calculated, and at the time $k$ that was used with the risk in mind.



    however, it is interesting to look at the median rather than expected pay off at time $t$, which can be found by assuming $median(Z_t)approx tp$.
    $$Y_k|Y_0=Y_0 (1+2q)^tp(1-q)^t(1-p)$$
    when $p=0.5$ the we have the ratio equal to $(1+q-2q^2)^0.5t$. This is maximised when $q=0.25$ and greater than $1$ when $q<0.5$



    it is also interesting to calculate the chance you will be ahead at time $t$. to do this we need to determine the value $z$ such that
    $$(1+2q)^z(1-q)^t-z>1$$
    doing some rearranging we find that the proportion of wins should satisfy
    $$fraczt>fraclog(1-q)log(1-q)-log(1+2q)$$
    This can be plugged into a normal approximation (note: mean of $0.5$ and standard error of $frac0.5sqrtt$) as
    $$Pr(textahead at time t)approxPhileft(sqrttfraclog(1+2q)+log(1-q)left[log(1+2q)-log(1-q)right]right)$$



    which clearly shows the game has very good odds. the factor multiplying $sqrtt$ is minimised when $q=0$ (maximised value of $frac13$) and is monotonically decreasing as a function of $q$. so the "low risk" strategy is to bet a very small fraction of your wealth, and play a large number of times.



    suppose we compare this with $q=frac13$ and $q=frac1100$. the factor for each case is $0.11$ and $0.32$. This means after $38$ games you would have around a 95% chance to be ahead with the small bet, compared to a 75% chance with the larger bet. Additionally, you also have a chance of going broke with the larger bet, assuming you had to round your stake to the nearest 5 cents or dollar. Starting with $20$ this could go $13.35, 8.90,5.95,3.95,2.65,1.75,1.15,0.75,0.50,0.35,0.25,0.15,0.1,0.05,0$.
    This is a sequence of $14$ losses out of $38$, and given the game would expect $19$ losses, if you get unlucky with the first few bets, then even winning may not make up for a bad streak (e.g., if most of your wins occur once most of the wealth is gone). going broke with the smaller 1% stake is not possible in $38$ games.
    The flip side is that the smaller stake will result in a much smaller profit on average, something like a $350$ fold increase with the large bet compared to $1.2$ increase with the small bet (i.e. you expect to have 24 dollars after 38 rounds with the small bet and 7000 dollars with the large bet).






    share|cite|improve this answer









    $endgroup$













      Your Answer





      StackExchange.ifUsing("editor", function ()
      return StackExchange.using("mathjaxEditing", function ()
      StackExchange.MarkdownEditor.creationCallbacks.add(function (editor, postfix)
      StackExchange.mathjaxEditing.prepareWmdForMathJax(editor, postfix, [["$", "$"], ["\\(","\\)"]]);
      );
      );
      , "mathjax-editing");

      StackExchange.ready(function()
      var channelOptions =
      tags: "".split(" "),
      id: "65"
      ;
      initTagRenderer("".split(" "), "".split(" "), channelOptions);

      StackExchange.using("externalEditor", function()
      // Have to fire editor after snippets, if snippets enabled
      if (StackExchange.settings.snippets.snippetsEnabled)
      StackExchange.using("snippets", function()
      createEditor();
      );

      else
      createEditor();

      );

      function createEditor()
      StackExchange.prepareEditor(
      heartbeatType: 'answer',
      autoActivateHeartbeat: false,
      convertImagesToLinks: false,
      noModals: true,
      showLowRepImageUploadWarning: true,
      reputationToPostImages: null,
      bindNavPrevention: true,
      postfix: "",
      imageUploader:
      brandingHtml: "Powered by u003ca class="icon-imgur-white" href="https://imgur.com/"u003eu003c/au003e",
      contentPolicyHtml: "User contributions licensed under u003ca href="https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/3.0/"u003ecc by-sa 3.0 with attribution requiredu003c/au003e u003ca href="https://stackoverflow.com/legal/content-policy"u003e(content policy)u003c/au003e",
      allowUrls: true
      ,
      onDemand: true,
      discardSelector: ".discard-answer"
      ,immediatelyShowMarkdownHelp:true
      );



      );






      ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor. Be nice, and check out our Code of Conduct.









      draft saved

      draft discarded


















      StackExchange.ready(
      function ()
      StackExchange.openid.initPostLogin('.new-post-login', 'https%3a%2f%2fstats.stackexchange.com%2fquestions%2f401480%2fthe-magic-money-tree-problem%23new-answer', 'question_page');

      );

      Post as a guest















      Required, but never shown

























      4 Answers
      4






      active

      oldest

      votes








      4 Answers
      4






      active

      oldest

      votes









      active

      oldest

      votes






      active

      oldest

      votes









      3












      $begingroup$

      This is a well-known problem. It is called a Kelly bet. The answer, by the way, is 1/3rd. It is equivalent to maximizing the log utility of wealth.



      Kelly began with taking time to infinity and then solving backward. Since you can always express returns in terms of continuous compounding, then you can also reverse the process and express it in logs. I am going to use the log utility explanation, but the log utility is a convenience. If you are maximizing wealth as $ntoinfty$ then you will end up with a function that works out to be the same as log utility. If $b$ is the payout odds, and $p$ is the probability of winning, and $X$ is the percentage of wealth invested, then the following derivation will work.



      For a binary bet, $E(log(X))=plog(1+bX)+(1-p)log(1-X)$, for a single period and unit wealth.



      $$fracddXE[log(x)]=fracddX[plog(1+bX)+(1-p)log(1-X)]$$
      $$=fracpb1+bX-frac1-p1-X$$



      Setting the derivative to zero to find the extrema,



      $$fracpb1+bX-frac1-p1-X=0$$



      Cross multiplying, you end up with $$pb(1-X)-(1-p)(1+bX)=0$$
      $$pb-pbX-1-bX+p+pbX=0$$
      $$bX=pb-1+p$$
      $$X=fracbp-(1-p)b$$



      In your case, $$X=frac3timesfrac12-(1-frac12)3=frac13.$$



      You can readily expand this to multiple or continuous outcomes by solving the expected utility of wealth over a joint probability distribution, choosing the allocations and subject to any constraints. Interestingly, if you perform it in this manner, by including constraints, such as the ability to meet mortgage payments and so forth, then you have accounted for your total set of risks and so you have a risk-adjusted or at least risk-controlled solution.



      Desiderata The actual purpose of the original research had to do with how much to gamble based on a noisy signal. In the specific case, how much to gamble on a noisy electronic signal where it indicated the launch of nuclear weapons by the Soviet Union. There have been several near launches by both the United States and Russia, obviously in error. How much do you gamble on a signal?






      share|cite|improve this answer









      $endgroup$












      • $begingroup$
        This strategy would give a higher risk of going broke I think compared to lower fractions
        $endgroup$
        – probabilityislogic
        3 hours ago










      • $begingroup$
        @probabilityislogic Only in the case where pennies exist. In the discrete case, it would become true because you could bet your last penny. You couldn't bet a third of a penny. In a discrete world, it is intrinsically true that the probability of bankruptcy must be increasing in allocation size, independent of the payoff case. A 2% allocation has a greater probability of bankruptcy than a 1% in a discrete world.
        $endgroup$
        – Dave Harris
        2 hours ago










      • $begingroup$
        @probabilityislogic if you begin with 3 cents then it is risky. If you start with $550 then there is less than one chance in 1024 of going bankrupt. For reasonable pot sizes, the risk of discrete collapse becomes small unless you really go to infinity, then it becomes a certainty unless borrowing is allowed.
        $endgroup$
        – Dave Harris
        2 hours ago
















      3












      $begingroup$

      This is a well-known problem. It is called a Kelly bet. The answer, by the way, is 1/3rd. It is equivalent to maximizing the log utility of wealth.



      Kelly began with taking time to infinity and then solving backward. Since you can always express returns in terms of continuous compounding, then you can also reverse the process and express it in logs. I am going to use the log utility explanation, but the log utility is a convenience. If you are maximizing wealth as $ntoinfty$ then you will end up with a function that works out to be the same as log utility. If $b$ is the payout odds, and $p$ is the probability of winning, and $X$ is the percentage of wealth invested, then the following derivation will work.



      For a binary bet, $E(log(X))=plog(1+bX)+(1-p)log(1-X)$, for a single period and unit wealth.



      $$fracddXE[log(x)]=fracddX[plog(1+bX)+(1-p)log(1-X)]$$
      $$=fracpb1+bX-frac1-p1-X$$



      Setting the derivative to zero to find the extrema,



      $$fracpb1+bX-frac1-p1-X=0$$



      Cross multiplying, you end up with $$pb(1-X)-(1-p)(1+bX)=0$$
      $$pb-pbX-1-bX+p+pbX=0$$
      $$bX=pb-1+p$$
      $$X=fracbp-(1-p)b$$



      In your case, $$X=frac3timesfrac12-(1-frac12)3=frac13.$$



      You can readily expand this to multiple or continuous outcomes by solving the expected utility of wealth over a joint probability distribution, choosing the allocations and subject to any constraints. Interestingly, if you perform it in this manner, by including constraints, such as the ability to meet mortgage payments and so forth, then you have accounted for your total set of risks and so you have a risk-adjusted or at least risk-controlled solution.



      Desiderata The actual purpose of the original research had to do with how much to gamble based on a noisy signal. In the specific case, how much to gamble on a noisy electronic signal where it indicated the launch of nuclear weapons by the Soviet Union. There have been several near launches by both the United States and Russia, obviously in error. How much do you gamble on a signal?






      share|cite|improve this answer









      $endgroup$












      • $begingroup$
        This strategy would give a higher risk of going broke I think compared to lower fractions
        $endgroup$
        – probabilityislogic
        3 hours ago










      • $begingroup$
        @probabilityislogic Only in the case where pennies exist. In the discrete case, it would become true because you could bet your last penny. You couldn't bet a third of a penny. In a discrete world, it is intrinsically true that the probability of bankruptcy must be increasing in allocation size, independent of the payoff case. A 2% allocation has a greater probability of bankruptcy than a 1% in a discrete world.
        $endgroup$
        – Dave Harris
        2 hours ago










      • $begingroup$
        @probabilityislogic if you begin with 3 cents then it is risky. If you start with $550 then there is less than one chance in 1024 of going bankrupt. For reasonable pot sizes, the risk of discrete collapse becomes small unless you really go to infinity, then it becomes a certainty unless borrowing is allowed.
        $endgroup$
        – Dave Harris
        2 hours ago














      3












      3








      3





      $begingroup$

      This is a well-known problem. It is called a Kelly bet. The answer, by the way, is 1/3rd. It is equivalent to maximizing the log utility of wealth.



      Kelly began with taking time to infinity and then solving backward. Since you can always express returns in terms of continuous compounding, then you can also reverse the process and express it in logs. I am going to use the log utility explanation, but the log utility is a convenience. If you are maximizing wealth as $ntoinfty$ then you will end up with a function that works out to be the same as log utility. If $b$ is the payout odds, and $p$ is the probability of winning, and $X$ is the percentage of wealth invested, then the following derivation will work.



      For a binary bet, $E(log(X))=plog(1+bX)+(1-p)log(1-X)$, for a single period and unit wealth.



      $$fracddXE[log(x)]=fracddX[plog(1+bX)+(1-p)log(1-X)]$$
      $$=fracpb1+bX-frac1-p1-X$$



      Setting the derivative to zero to find the extrema,



      $$fracpb1+bX-frac1-p1-X=0$$



      Cross multiplying, you end up with $$pb(1-X)-(1-p)(1+bX)=0$$
      $$pb-pbX-1-bX+p+pbX=0$$
      $$bX=pb-1+p$$
      $$X=fracbp-(1-p)b$$



      In your case, $$X=frac3timesfrac12-(1-frac12)3=frac13.$$



      You can readily expand this to multiple or continuous outcomes by solving the expected utility of wealth over a joint probability distribution, choosing the allocations and subject to any constraints. Interestingly, if you perform it in this manner, by including constraints, such as the ability to meet mortgage payments and so forth, then you have accounted for your total set of risks and so you have a risk-adjusted or at least risk-controlled solution.



      Desiderata The actual purpose of the original research had to do with how much to gamble based on a noisy signal. In the specific case, how much to gamble on a noisy electronic signal where it indicated the launch of nuclear weapons by the Soviet Union. There have been several near launches by both the United States and Russia, obviously in error. How much do you gamble on a signal?






      share|cite|improve this answer









      $endgroup$



      This is a well-known problem. It is called a Kelly bet. The answer, by the way, is 1/3rd. It is equivalent to maximizing the log utility of wealth.



      Kelly began with taking time to infinity and then solving backward. Since you can always express returns in terms of continuous compounding, then you can also reverse the process and express it in logs. I am going to use the log utility explanation, but the log utility is a convenience. If you are maximizing wealth as $ntoinfty$ then you will end up with a function that works out to be the same as log utility. If $b$ is the payout odds, and $p$ is the probability of winning, and $X$ is the percentage of wealth invested, then the following derivation will work.



      For a binary bet, $E(log(X))=plog(1+bX)+(1-p)log(1-X)$, for a single period and unit wealth.



      $$fracddXE[log(x)]=fracddX[plog(1+bX)+(1-p)log(1-X)]$$
      $$=fracpb1+bX-frac1-p1-X$$



      Setting the derivative to zero to find the extrema,



      $$fracpb1+bX-frac1-p1-X=0$$



      Cross multiplying, you end up with $$pb(1-X)-(1-p)(1+bX)=0$$
      $$pb-pbX-1-bX+p+pbX=0$$
      $$bX=pb-1+p$$
      $$X=fracbp-(1-p)b$$



      In your case, $$X=frac3timesfrac12-(1-frac12)3=frac13.$$



      You can readily expand this to multiple or continuous outcomes by solving the expected utility of wealth over a joint probability distribution, choosing the allocations and subject to any constraints. Interestingly, if you perform it in this manner, by including constraints, such as the ability to meet mortgage payments and so forth, then you have accounted for your total set of risks and so you have a risk-adjusted or at least risk-controlled solution.



      Desiderata The actual purpose of the original research had to do with how much to gamble based on a noisy signal. In the specific case, how much to gamble on a noisy electronic signal where it indicated the launch of nuclear weapons by the Soviet Union. There have been several near launches by both the United States and Russia, obviously in error. How much do you gamble on a signal?







      share|cite|improve this answer












      share|cite|improve this answer



      share|cite|improve this answer










      answered 7 hours ago









      Dave HarrisDave Harris

      3,797515




      3,797515











      • $begingroup$
        This strategy would give a higher risk of going broke I think compared to lower fractions
        $endgroup$
        – probabilityislogic
        3 hours ago










      • $begingroup$
        @probabilityislogic Only in the case where pennies exist. In the discrete case, it would become true because you could bet your last penny. You couldn't bet a third of a penny. In a discrete world, it is intrinsically true that the probability of bankruptcy must be increasing in allocation size, independent of the payoff case. A 2% allocation has a greater probability of bankruptcy than a 1% in a discrete world.
        $endgroup$
        – Dave Harris
        2 hours ago










      • $begingroup$
        @probabilityislogic if you begin with 3 cents then it is risky. If you start with $550 then there is less than one chance in 1024 of going bankrupt. For reasonable pot sizes, the risk of discrete collapse becomes small unless you really go to infinity, then it becomes a certainty unless borrowing is allowed.
        $endgroup$
        – Dave Harris
        2 hours ago

















      • $begingroup$
        This strategy would give a higher risk of going broke I think compared to lower fractions
        $endgroup$
        – probabilityislogic
        3 hours ago










      • $begingroup$
        @probabilityislogic Only in the case where pennies exist. In the discrete case, it would become true because you could bet your last penny. You couldn't bet a third of a penny. In a discrete world, it is intrinsically true that the probability of bankruptcy must be increasing in allocation size, independent of the payoff case. A 2% allocation has a greater probability of bankruptcy than a 1% in a discrete world.
        $endgroup$
        – Dave Harris
        2 hours ago










      • $begingroup$
        @probabilityislogic if you begin with 3 cents then it is risky. If you start with $550 then there is less than one chance in 1024 of going bankrupt. For reasonable pot sizes, the risk of discrete collapse becomes small unless you really go to infinity, then it becomes a certainty unless borrowing is allowed.
        $endgroup$
        – Dave Harris
        2 hours ago
















      $begingroup$
      This strategy would give a higher risk of going broke I think compared to lower fractions
      $endgroup$
      – probabilityislogic
      3 hours ago




      $begingroup$
      This strategy would give a higher risk of going broke I think compared to lower fractions
      $endgroup$
      – probabilityislogic
      3 hours ago












      $begingroup$
      @probabilityislogic Only in the case where pennies exist. In the discrete case, it would become true because you could bet your last penny. You couldn't bet a third of a penny. In a discrete world, it is intrinsically true that the probability of bankruptcy must be increasing in allocation size, independent of the payoff case. A 2% allocation has a greater probability of bankruptcy than a 1% in a discrete world.
      $endgroup$
      – Dave Harris
      2 hours ago




      $begingroup$
      @probabilityislogic Only in the case where pennies exist. In the discrete case, it would become true because you could bet your last penny. You couldn't bet a third of a penny. In a discrete world, it is intrinsically true that the probability of bankruptcy must be increasing in allocation size, independent of the payoff case. A 2% allocation has a greater probability of bankruptcy than a 1% in a discrete world.
      $endgroup$
      – Dave Harris
      2 hours ago












      $begingroup$
      @probabilityislogic if you begin with 3 cents then it is risky. If you start with $550 then there is less than one chance in 1024 of going bankrupt. For reasonable pot sizes, the risk of discrete collapse becomes small unless you really go to infinity, then it becomes a certainty unless borrowing is allowed.
      $endgroup$
      – Dave Harris
      2 hours ago





      $begingroup$
      @probabilityislogic if you begin with 3 cents then it is risky. If you start with $550 then there is less than one chance in 1024 of going bankrupt. For reasonable pot sizes, the risk of discrete collapse becomes small unless you really go to infinity, then it becomes a certainty unless borrowing is allowed.
      $endgroup$
      – Dave Harris
      2 hours ago














      2












      $begingroup$

      I don't think this is much different from the Martingale. In your case, there are no doubling bets, but the winning payout is 3x.



      I coded a "replica" of your tree. I run 10 simulations. In each simulation (trace), you start with 200 coins and try with the tree, 1 coin each time for 20000 times.



      The only conditions that stop the simulation are bankruptcy or having "survived" 20k attempts



      enter image description here



      So long as the winning odds are 50% or less, sooner or later bankruptcy awaits you.






      share|cite|improve this answer








      New contributor




      Carles Alcolea is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
      Check out our Code of Conduct.






      $endgroup$












      • $begingroup$
        Are you able to post the code that you wrote for this as well please?
        $endgroup$
        – baxx
        10 hours ago















      2












      $begingroup$

      I don't think this is much different from the Martingale. In your case, there are no doubling bets, but the winning payout is 3x.



      I coded a "replica" of your tree. I run 10 simulations. In each simulation (trace), you start with 200 coins and try with the tree, 1 coin each time for 20000 times.



      The only conditions that stop the simulation are bankruptcy or having "survived" 20k attempts



      enter image description here



      So long as the winning odds are 50% or less, sooner or later bankruptcy awaits you.






      share|cite|improve this answer








      New contributor




      Carles Alcolea is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
      Check out our Code of Conduct.






      $endgroup$












      • $begingroup$
        Are you able to post the code that you wrote for this as well please?
        $endgroup$
        – baxx
        10 hours ago













      2












      2








      2





      $begingroup$

      I don't think this is much different from the Martingale. In your case, there are no doubling bets, but the winning payout is 3x.



      I coded a "replica" of your tree. I run 10 simulations. In each simulation (trace), you start with 200 coins and try with the tree, 1 coin each time for 20000 times.



      The only conditions that stop the simulation are bankruptcy or having "survived" 20k attempts



      enter image description here



      So long as the winning odds are 50% or less, sooner or later bankruptcy awaits you.






      share|cite|improve this answer








      New contributor




      Carles Alcolea is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
      Check out our Code of Conduct.






      $endgroup$



      I don't think this is much different from the Martingale. In your case, there are no doubling bets, but the winning payout is 3x.



      I coded a "replica" of your tree. I run 10 simulations. In each simulation (trace), you start with 200 coins and try with the tree, 1 coin each time for 20000 times.



      The only conditions that stop the simulation are bankruptcy or having "survived" 20k attempts



      enter image description here



      So long as the winning odds are 50% or less, sooner or later bankruptcy awaits you.







      share|cite|improve this answer








      New contributor




      Carles Alcolea is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
      Check out our Code of Conduct.









      share|cite|improve this answer



      share|cite|improve this answer






      New contributor




      Carles Alcolea is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
      Check out our Code of Conduct.









      answered 12 hours ago









      Carles AlcoleaCarles Alcolea

      1212




      1212




      New contributor




      Carles Alcolea is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
      Check out our Code of Conduct.





      New contributor





      Carles Alcolea is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
      Check out our Code of Conduct.






      Carles Alcolea is a new contributor to this site. Take care in asking for clarification, commenting, and answering.
      Check out our Code of Conduct.











      • $begingroup$
        Are you able to post the code that you wrote for this as well please?
        $endgroup$
        – baxx
        10 hours ago
















      • $begingroup$
        Are you able to post the code that you wrote for this as well please?
        $endgroup$
        – baxx
        10 hours ago















      $begingroup$
      Are you able to post the code that you wrote for this as well please?
      $endgroup$
      – baxx
      10 hours ago




      $begingroup$
      Are you able to post the code that you wrote for this as well please?
      $endgroup$
      – baxx
      10 hours ago











      1












      $begingroup$



      Problem statement



      Let $Y_t = log_10(M_t)$ be the logarithm of the amount of money $M_t$ the gambler has at time $t$.



      • The gambler starts with $$Y_0 = S = 1$$.


      • The gambler goes banckrupt whenever $$Y_t< L = -2$$.


      Simplification.



      • The gambler stops gambling when he has passed some amount of money $$Y_t > W = 7$$

      Random walk



      Let $b$ be the fraction of money that you are betting. You can see the growth and decline of the money as an asymmetric random walk. That is you can describe $Y_t$ as:



      $$Y_t = Y_0 + sum_i=1^t X_i$$



      where



      $$mathbbP[X_i= a_w =log(1+2b)] = mathbbP[X_i= a_l =log(1-b)] = frac12$$



      Martingale



      The expression



      $$Z_t = c^Y_t$$



      is a martingale when we choose $c$ such that.



      $$c^a_w+ c^a_l = 2$$ (where $c<1$ if $b<0.5$). Since in that case



      $$E[Z_t+1] = E[Z_t] frac12 c^a_w + E[Z_t] frac12 c^a_l = E[Z_t]$$



      Probability to end up bankrupt



      The stopping time (bankrupty $Y_t < L$ or winning $Y_t>W$) is almost surely finite, since it requires in the worst case a winning streak (or loosing streak) of a certain finite length, $fracW-Sa_w$, which is almost surely gonna happen.



      Then, we can use the optional stopping theorem to say $E[Z_tau]$ at the stopping time $tau$ equals the expected value $E[Z_0]$ at time zero.



      Thus



      $$c^S = E[Z_0] = E[Z_tau] approx mathbbP[Y_tau<L] c^L + (1-mathbbP[Y_tau<L]) c^W$$



      and



      $$ mathbbP[Y_tau<L] approx fracc^S-c^Wc^L-c^W$$



      and the limit $W to infty$



      $$ mathbbP[Y_tau<L] approx c^S-L$$



      Conclusion



      When the gambler bets less than half the money (such that $c<1$) then the gambler will not certainly go bankrupt, and the probability to end up bankrupt will be less when the gambler is betting with a smaller fraction.



      Simulations



      simulations



      # functions to compute c
      cx = function(c,x)
      c^log(1-x,10)+c^log(1+2*x,10) - 2

      findc = function(x)
      r <- uniroot(cx, c(0,1-0.1^10),x=x,tol=10^-130)
      r$root



      # settings
      set.seed(1)
      n <- 100000
      n2 <- 1000
      b <- 0.45

      # repeating different betting strategies
      for (b in c(0.35,0.4,0.45))
      # plot empty canvas
      plot(1,-1000,
      xlim=c(0,n2),ylim=c(-2,50),
      type="l",
      xlab = "time step", ylab = expression(log[10](M[t])) )

      # steps in the logarithm of the money
      steps <- c(log(1+2*b,10),log(1-b,10))

      # counter for number of bankrupts
      bank <- 0

      # computing 1000 times
      for (i in 1:1000)
      # sampling wins or looses
      X_t <- sample(steps, n, replace = TRUE)
      # compute log of money
      Y_t <- 1+cumsum(X_t)
      # compute money
      M_t <- 10^Y_t
      # optional stopping (bankruptcy)
      tau <- min(c(n,which(-2 > Y_t)))
      if (tau<n)
      bank <- bank+1

      # plot only 100 to prevent clutter
      if (i<=100)
      col=rgb(tau<n,0,0,0.5)
      lines(1:tau,Y_t[1:tau],col=col)


      text(0,45,paste0(bank, " bankruptcies out of 1000 n", "theoretic bankruptcy rate is ", round(findc(b)^3,4)),cex=1,pos=4)
      title(paste0("betting a fraction ", round(b,2)))






      share|cite|improve this answer











      $endgroup$

















        1












        $begingroup$



        Problem statement



        Let $Y_t = log_10(M_t)$ be the logarithm of the amount of money $M_t$ the gambler has at time $t$.



        • The gambler starts with $$Y_0 = S = 1$$.


        • The gambler goes banckrupt whenever $$Y_t< L = -2$$.


        Simplification.



        • The gambler stops gambling when he has passed some amount of money $$Y_t > W = 7$$

        Random walk



        Let $b$ be the fraction of money that you are betting. You can see the growth and decline of the money as an asymmetric random walk. That is you can describe $Y_t$ as:



        $$Y_t = Y_0 + sum_i=1^t X_i$$



        where



        $$mathbbP[X_i= a_w =log(1+2b)] = mathbbP[X_i= a_l =log(1-b)] = frac12$$



        Martingale



        The expression



        $$Z_t = c^Y_t$$



        is a martingale when we choose $c$ such that.



        $$c^a_w+ c^a_l = 2$$ (where $c<1$ if $b<0.5$). Since in that case



        $$E[Z_t+1] = E[Z_t] frac12 c^a_w + E[Z_t] frac12 c^a_l = E[Z_t]$$



        Probability to end up bankrupt



        The stopping time (bankrupty $Y_t < L$ or winning $Y_t>W$) is almost surely finite, since it requires in the worst case a winning streak (or loosing streak) of a certain finite length, $fracW-Sa_w$, which is almost surely gonna happen.



        Then, we can use the optional stopping theorem to say $E[Z_tau]$ at the stopping time $tau$ equals the expected value $E[Z_0]$ at time zero.



        Thus



        $$c^S = E[Z_0] = E[Z_tau] approx mathbbP[Y_tau<L] c^L + (1-mathbbP[Y_tau<L]) c^W$$



        and



        $$ mathbbP[Y_tau<L] approx fracc^S-c^Wc^L-c^W$$



        and the limit $W to infty$



        $$ mathbbP[Y_tau<L] approx c^S-L$$



        Conclusion



        When the gambler bets less than half the money (such that $c<1$) then the gambler will not certainly go bankrupt, and the probability to end up bankrupt will be less when the gambler is betting with a smaller fraction.



        Simulations



        simulations



        # functions to compute c
        cx = function(c,x)
        c^log(1-x,10)+c^log(1+2*x,10) - 2

        findc = function(x)
        r <- uniroot(cx, c(0,1-0.1^10),x=x,tol=10^-130)
        r$root



        # settings
        set.seed(1)
        n <- 100000
        n2 <- 1000
        b <- 0.45

        # repeating different betting strategies
        for (b in c(0.35,0.4,0.45))
        # plot empty canvas
        plot(1,-1000,
        xlim=c(0,n2),ylim=c(-2,50),
        type="l",
        xlab = "time step", ylab = expression(log[10](M[t])) )

        # steps in the logarithm of the money
        steps <- c(log(1+2*b,10),log(1-b,10))

        # counter for number of bankrupts
        bank <- 0

        # computing 1000 times
        for (i in 1:1000)
        # sampling wins or looses
        X_t <- sample(steps, n, replace = TRUE)
        # compute log of money
        Y_t <- 1+cumsum(X_t)
        # compute money
        M_t <- 10^Y_t
        # optional stopping (bankruptcy)
        tau <- min(c(n,which(-2 > Y_t)))
        if (tau<n)
        bank <- bank+1

        # plot only 100 to prevent clutter
        if (i<=100)
        col=rgb(tau<n,0,0,0.5)
        lines(1:tau,Y_t[1:tau],col=col)


        text(0,45,paste0(bank, " bankruptcies out of 1000 n", "theoretic bankruptcy rate is ", round(findc(b)^3,4)),cex=1,pos=4)
        title(paste0("betting a fraction ", round(b,2)))






        share|cite|improve this answer











        $endgroup$















          1












          1








          1





          $begingroup$



          Problem statement



          Let $Y_t = log_10(M_t)$ be the logarithm of the amount of money $M_t$ the gambler has at time $t$.



          • The gambler starts with $$Y_0 = S = 1$$.


          • The gambler goes banckrupt whenever $$Y_t< L = -2$$.


          Simplification.



          • The gambler stops gambling when he has passed some amount of money $$Y_t > W = 7$$

          Random walk



          Let $b$ be the fraction of money that you are betting. You can see the growth and decline of the money as an asymmetric random walk. That is you can describe $Y_t$ as:



          $$Y_t = Y_0 + sum_i=1^t X_i$$



          where



          $$mathbbP[X_i= a_w =log(1+2b)] = mathbbP[X_i= a_l =log(1-b)] = frac12$$



          Martingale



          The expression



          $$Z_t = c^Y_t$$



          is a martingale when we choose $c$ such that.



          $$c^a_w+ c^a_l = 2$$ (where $c<1$ if $b<0.5$). Since in that case



          $$E[Z_t+1] = E[Z_t] frac12 c^a_w + E[Z_t] frac12 c^a_l = E[Z_t]$$



          Probability to end up bankrupt



          The stopping time (bankrupty $Y_t < L$ or winning $Y_t>W$) is almost surely finite, since it requires in the worst case a winning streak (or loosing streak) of a certain finite length, $fracW-Sa_w$, which is almost surely gonna happen.



          Then, we can use the optional stopping theorem to say $E[Z_tau]$ at the stopping time $tau$ equals the expected value $E[Z_0]$ at time zero.



          Thus



          $$c^S = E[Z_0] = E[Z_tau] approx mathbbP[Y_tau<L] c^L + (1-mathbbP[Y_tau<L]) c^W$$



          and



          $$ mathbbP[Y_tau<L] approx fracc^S-c^Wc^L-c^W$$



          and the limit $W to infty$



          $$ mathbbP[Y_tau<L] approx c^S-L$$



          Conclusion



          When the gambler bets less than half the money (such that $c<1$) then the gambler will not certainly go bankrupt, and the probability to end up bankrupt will be less when the gambler is betting with a smaller fraction.



          Simulations



          simulations



          # functions to compute c
          cx = function(c,x)
          c^log(1-x,10)+c^log(1+2*x,10) - 2

          findc = function(x)
          r <- uniroot(cx, c(0,1-0.1^10),x=x,tol=10^-130)
          r$root



          # settings
          set.seed(1)
          n <- 100000
          n2 <- 1000
          b <- 0.45

          # repeating different betting strategies
          for (b in c(0.35,0.4,0.45))
          # plot empty canvas
          plot(1,-1000,
          xlim=c(0,n2),ylim=c(-2,50),
          type="l",
          xlab = "time step", ylab = expression(log[10](M[t])) )

          # steps in the logarithm of the money
          steps <- c(log(1+2*b,10),log(1-b,10))

          # counter for number of bankrupts
          bank <- 0

          # computing 1000 times
          for (i in 1:1000)
          # sampling wins or looses
          X_t <- sample(steps, n, replace = TRUE)
          # compute log of money
          Y_t <- 1+cumsum(X_t)
          # compute money
          M_t <- 10^Y_t
          # optional stopping (bankruptcy)
          tau <- min(c(n,which(-2 > Y_t)))
          if (tau<n)
          bank <- bank+1

          # plot only 100 to prevent clutter
          if (i<=100)
          col=rgb(tau<n,0,0,0.5)
          lines(1:tau,Y_t[1:tau],col=col)


          text(0,45,paste0(bank, " bankruptcies out of 1000 n", "theoretic bankruptcy rate is ", round(findc(b)^3,4)),cex=1,pos=4)
          title(paste0("betting a fraction ", round(b,2)))






          share|cite|improve this answer











          $endgroup$





          Problem statement



          Let $Y_t = log_10(M_t)$ be the logarithm of the amount of money $M_t$ the gambler has at time $t$.



          • The gambler starts with $$Y_0 = S = 1$$.


          • The gambler goes banckrupt whenever $$Y_t< L = -2$$.


          Simplification.



          • The gambler stops gambling when he has passed some amount of money $$Y_t > W = 7$$

          Random walk



          Let $b$ be the fraction of money that you are betting. You can see the growth and decline of the money as an asymmetric random walk. That is you can describe $Y_t$ as:



          $$Y_t = Y_0 + sum_i=1^t X_i$$



          where



          $$mathbbP[X_i= a_w =log(1+2b)] = mathbbP[X_i= a_l =log(1-b)] = frac12$$



          Martingale



          The expression



          $$Z_t = c^Y_t$$



          is a martingale when we choose $c$ such that.



          $$c^a_w+ c^a_l = 2$$ (where $c<1$ if $b<0.5$). Since in that case



          $$E[Z_t+1] = E[Z_t] frac12 c^a_w + E[Z_t] frac12 c^a_l = E[Z_t]$$



          Probability to end up bankrupt



          The stopping time (bankrupty $Y_t < L$ or winning $Y_t>W$) is almost surely finite, since it requires in the worst case a winning streak (or loosing streak) of a certain finite length, $fracW-Sa_w$, which is almost surely gonna happen.



          Then, we can use the optional stopping theorem to say $E[Z_tau]$ at the stopping time $tau$ equals the expected value $E[Z_0]$ at time zero.



          Thus



          $$c^S = E[Z_0] = E[Z_tau] approx mathbbP[Y_tau<L] c^L + (1-mathbbP[Y_tau<L]) c^W$$



          and



          $$ mathbbP[Y_tau<L] approx fracc^S-c^Wc^L-c^W$$



          and the limit $W to infty$



          $$ mathbbP[Y_tau<L] approx c^S-L$$



          Conclusion



          When the gambler bets less than half the money (such that $c<1$) then the gambler will not certainly go bankrupt, and the probability to end up bankrupt will be less when the gambler is betting with a smaller fraction.



          Simulations



          simulations



          # functions to compute c
          cx = function(c,x)
          c^log(1-x,10)+c^log(1+2*x,10) - 2

          findc = function(x)
          r <- uniroot(cx, c(0,1-0.1^10),x=x,tol=10^-130)
          r$root



          # settings
          set.seed(1)
          n <- 100000
          n2 <- 1000
          b <- 0.45

          # repeating different betting strategies
          for (b in c(0.35,0.4,0.45))
          # plot empty canvas
          plot(1,-1000,
          xlim=c(0,n2),ylim=c(-2,50),
          type="l",
          xlab = "time step", ylab = expression(log[10](M[t])) )

          # steps in the logarithm of the money
          steps <- c(log(1+2*b,10),log(1-b,10))

          # counter for number of bankrupts
          bank <- 0

          # computing 1000 times
          for (i in 1:1000)
          # sampling wins or looses
          X_t <- sample(steps, n, replace = TRUE)
          # compute log of money
          Y_t <- 1+cumsum(X_t)
          # compute money
          M_t <- 10^Y_t
          # optional stopping (bankruptcy)
          tau <- min(c(n,which(-2 > Y_t)))
          if (tau<n)
          bank <- bank+1

          # plot only 100 to prevent clutter
          if (i<=100)
          col=rgb(tau<n,0,0,0.5)
          lines(1:tau,Y_t[1:tau],col=col)


          text(0,45,paste0(bank, " bankruptcies out of 1000 n", "theoretic bankruptcy rate is ", round(findc(b)^3,4)),cex=1,pos=4)
          title(paste0("betting a fraction ", round(b,2)))







          share|cite|improve this answer














          share|cite|improve this answer



          share|cite|improve this answer








          edited 8 hours ago

























          answered 12 hours ago









          Martijn WeteringsMartijn Weterings

          14.9k1964




          14.9k1964





















              1












              $begingroup$

              I liked the answer given by Dave harris. just though I would come at the problem from a "low risk" perspective, rather than profit maximising



              The random walk you are doing, assuming your fraction bet is $q$ and probability of winning $p=0.5$ has is given as
              $$Y_t|Y_t-1=(1-q+3qX_t)Y_t-1$$
              where $X_tsim Bernoulli(p)$. on average you have
              $$E(Y_t|Y_t-1) = (1-q+3pq)Y_t-1$$
              You can iteratively apply this to get
              $$Y_t|Y_0=Y_0prod_j=1^t (1-q+3qX_t)$$
              with expected value
              $$E(Y_t|Y_0) = (1-q+3pq)^t Y_0$$
              you can also express the amount at time $t$ as a function of a single random variable $Z_t=sum_j=1^t X_tsim Binomial(t,p)$, but noting that $Z_t$ is not independent from $Z_t-1$
              $$Y_t|Y_0=Y_0 (1+2q)^Z_t(1-q)^t-Z_t$$



              possible strategy



              you could use this formula to determine a "low risk" value for $q$. Say assuming you wanted to ensure that after $k$ consecutive losses you still had half your original wealth. Then you set $q=1-2^-k^-1$



              Taking the example $k=5$ means we set $q=0.129$, or with $k=15$ we set $q=0.045$.



              Also, due to the recursive nature of the strategy, this risk is what you are taking every at every single bet. That is, at time $s$, by continuing to play you are ensuring that at time $k+s$ your wealth will be at least $0.5Y_s$



              discussion



              the above strategy does not depend on the pay off from winning, but rather about setting a boundary on losing. We can get the expected winnings by substituting in the value for $q$ we calculated, and at the time $k$ that was used with the risk in mind.



              however, it is interesting to look at the median rather than expected pay off at time $t$, which can be found by assuming $median(Z_t)approx tp$.
              $$Y_k|Y_0=Y_0 (1+2q)^tp(1-q)^t(1-p)$$
              when $p=0.5$ the we have the ratio equal to $(1+q-2q^2)^0.5t$. This is maximised when $q=0.25$ and greater than $1$ when $q<0.5$



              it is also interesting to calculate the chance you will be ahead at time $t$. to do this we need to determine the value $z$ such that
              $$(1+2q)^z(1-q)^t-z>1$$
              doing some rearranging we find that the proportion of wins should satisfy
              $$fraczt>fraclog(1-q)log(1-q)-log(1+2q)$$
              This can be plugged into a normal approximation (note: mean of $0.5$ and standard error of $frac0.5sqrtt$) as
              $$Pr(textahead at time t)approxPhileft(sqrttfraclog(1+2q)+log(1-q)left[log(1+2q)-log(1-q)right]right)$$



              which clearly shows the game has very good odds. the factor multiplying $sqrtt$ is minimised when $q=0$ (maximised value of $frac13$) and is monotonically decreasing as a function of $q$. so the "low risk" strategy is to bet a very small fraction of your wealth, and play a large number of times.



              suppose we compare this with $q=frac13$ and $q=frac1100$. the factor for each case is $0.11$ and $0.32$. This means after $38$ games you would have around a 95% chance to be ahead with the small bet, compared to a 75% chance with the larger bet. Additionally, you also have a chance of going broke with the larger bet, assuming you had to round your stake to the nearest 5 cents or dollar. Starting with $20$ this could go $13.35, 8.90,5.95,3.95,2.65,1.75,1.15,0.75,0.50,0.35,0.25,0.15,0.1,0.05,0$.
              This is a sequence of $14$ losses out of $38$, and given the game would expect $19$ losses, if you get unlucky with the first few bets, then even winning may not make up for a bad streak (e.g., if most of your wins occur once most of the wealth is gone). going broke with the smaller 1% stake is not possible in $38$ games.
              The flip side is that the smaller stake will result in a much smaller profit on average, something like a $350$ fold increase with the large bet compared to $1.2$ increase with the small bet (i.e. you expect to have 24 dollars after 38 rounds with the small bet and 7000 dollars with the large bet).






              share|cite|improve this answer









              $endgroup$

















                1












                $begingroup$

                I liked the answer given by Dave harris. just though I would come at the problem from a "low risk" perspective, rather than profit maximising



                The random walk you are doing, assuming your fraction bet is $q$ and probability of winning $p=0.5$ has is given as
                $$Y_t|Y_t-1=(1-q+3qX_t)Y_t-1$$
                where $X_tsim Bernoulli(p)$. on average you have
                $$E(Y_t|Y_t-1) = (1-q+3pq)Y_t-1$$
                You can iteratively apply this to get
                $$Y_t|Y_0=Y_0prod_j=1^t (1-q+3qX_t)$$
                with expected value
                $$E(Y_t|Y_0) = (1-q+3pq)^t Y_0$$
                you can also express the amount at time $t$ as a function of a single random variable $Z_t=sum_j=1^t X_tsim Binomial(t,p)$, but noting that $Z_t$ is not independent from $Z_t-1$
                $$Y_t|Y_0=Y_0 (1+2q)^Z_t(1-q)^t-Z_t$$



                possible strategy



                you could use this formula to determine a "low risk" value for $q$. Say assuming you wanted to ensure that after $k$ consecutive losses you still had half your original wealth. Then you set $q=1-2^-k^-1$



                Taking the example $k=5$ means we set $q=0.129$, or with $k=15$ we set $q=0.045$.



                Also, due to the recursive nature of the strategy, this risk is what you are taking every at every single bet. That is, at time $s$, by continuing to play you are ensuring that at time $k+s$ your wealth will be at least $0.5Y_s$



                discussion



                the above strategy does not depend on the pay off from winning, but rather about setting a boundary on losing. We can get the expected winnings by substituting in the value for $q$ we calculated, and at the time $k$ that was used with the risk in mind.



                however, it is interesting to look at the median rather than expected pay off at time $t$, which can be found by assuming $median(Z_t)approx tp$.
                $$Y_k|Y_0=Y_0 (1+2q)^tp(1-q)^t(1-p)$$
                when $p=0.5$ the we have the ratio equal to $(1+q-2q^2)^0.5t$. This is maximised when $q=0.25$ and greater than $1$ when $q<0.5$



                it is also interesting to calculate the chance you will be ahead at time $t$. to do this we need to determine the value $z$ such that
                $$(1+2q)^z(1-q)^t-z>1$$
                doing some rearranging we find that the proportion of wins should satisfy
                $$fraczt>fraclog(1-q)log(1-q)-log(1+2q)$$
                This can be plugged into a normal approximation (note: mean of $0.5$ and standard error of $frac0.5sqrtt$) as
                $$Pr(textahead at time t)approxPhileft(sqrttfraclog(1+2q)+log(1-q)left[log(1+2q)-log(1-q)right]right)$$



                which clearly shows the game has very good odds. the factor multiplying $sqrtt$ is minimised when $q=0$ (maximised value of $frac13$) and is monotonically decreasing as a function of $q$. so the "low risk" strategy is to bet a very small fraction of your wealth, and play a large number of times.



                suppose we compare this with $q=frac13$ and $q=frac1100$. the factor for each case is $0.11$ and $0.32$. This means after $38$ games you would have around a 95% chance to be ahead with the small bet, compared to a 75% chance with the larger bet. Additionally, you also have a chance of going broke with the larger bet, assuming you had to round your stake to the nearest 5 cents or dollar. Starting with $20$ this could go $13.35, 8.90,5.95,3.95,2.65,1.75,1.15,0.75,0.50,0.35,0.25,0.15,0.1,0.05,0$.
                This is a sequence of $14$ losses out of $38$, and given the game would expect $19$ losses, if you get unlucky with the first few bets, then even winning may not make up for a bad streak (e.g., if most of your wins occur once most of the wealth is gone). going broke with the smaller 1% stake is not possible in $38$ games.
                The flip side is that the smaller stake will result in a much smaller profit on average, something like a $350$ fold increase with the large bet compared to $1.2$ increase with the small bet (i.e. you expect to have 24 dollars after 38 rounds with the small bet and 7000 dollars with the large bet).






                share|cite|improve this answer









                $endgroup$















                  1












                  1








                  1





                  $begingroup$

                  I liked the answer given by Dave harris. just though I would come at the problem from a "low risk" perspective, rather than profit maximising



                  The random walk you are doing, assuming your fraction bet is $q$ and probability of winning $p=0.5$ has is given as
                  $$Y_t|Y_t-1=(1-q+3qX_t)Y_t-1$$
                  where $X_tsim Bernoulli(p)$. on average you have
                  $$E(Y_t|Y_t-1) = (1-q+3pq)Y_t-1$$
                  You can iteratively apply this to get
                  $$Y_t|Y_0=Y_0prod_j=1^t (1-q+3qX_t)$$
                  with expected value
                  $$E(Y_t|Y_0) = (1-q+3pq)^t Y_0$$
                  you can also express the amount at time $t$ as a function of a single random variable $Z_t=sum_j=1^t X_tsim Binomial(t,p)$, but noting that $Z_t$ is not independent from $Z_t-1$
                  $$Y_t|Y_0=Y_0 (1+2q)^Z_t(1-q)^t-Z_t$$



                  possible strategy



                  you could use this formula to determine a "low risk" value for $q$. Say assuming you wanted to ensure that after $k$ consecutive losses you still had half your original wealth. Then you set $q=1-2^-k^-1$



                  Taking the example $k=5$ means we set $q=0.129$, or with $k=15$ we set $q=0.045$.



                  Also, due to the recursive nature of the strategy, this risk is what you are taking every at every single bet. That is, at time $s$, by continuing to play you are ensuring that at time $k+s$ your wealth will be at least $0.5Y_s$



                  discussion



                  the above strategy does not depend on the pay off from winning, but rather about setting a boundary on losing. We can get the expected winnings by substituting in the value for $q$ we calculated, and at the time $k$ that was used with the risk in mind.



                  however, it is interesting to look at the median rather than expected pay off at time $t$, which can be found by assuming $median(Z_t)approx tp$.
                  $$Y_k|Y_0=Y_0 (1+2q)^tp(1-q)^t(1-p)$$
                  when $p=0.5$ the we have the ratio equal to $(1+q-2q^2)^0.5t$. This is maximised when $q=0.25$ and greater than $1$ when $q<0.5$



                  it is also interesting to calculate the chance you will be ahead at time $t$. to do this we need to determine the value $z$ such that
                  $$(1+2q)^z(1-q)^t-z>1$$
                  doing some rearranging we find that the proportion of wins should satisfy
                  $$fraczt>fraclog(1-q)log(1-q)-log(1+2q)$$
                  This can be plugged into a normal approximation (note: mean of $0.5$ and standard error of $frac0.5sqrtt$) as
                  $$Pr(textahead at time t)approxPhileft(sqrttfraclog(1+2q)+log(1-q)left[log(1+2q)-log(1-q)right]right)$$



                  which clearly shows the game has very good odds. the factor multiplying $sqrtt$ is minimised when $q=0$ (maximised value of $frac13$) and is monotonically decreasing as a function of $q$. so the "low risk" strategy is to bet a very small fraction of your wealth, and play a large number of times.



                  suppose we compare this with $q=frac13$ and $q=frac1100$. the factor for each case is $0.11$ and $0.32$. This means after $38$ games you would have around a 95% chance to be ahead with the small bet, compared to a 75% chance with the larger bet. Additionally, you also have a chance of going broke with the larger bet, assuming you had to round your stake to the nearest 5 cents or dollar. Starting with $20$ this could go $13.35, 8.90,5.95,3.95,2.65,1.75,1.15,0.75,0.50,0.35,0.25,0.15,0.1,0.05,0$.
                  This is a sequence of $14$ losses out of $38$, and given the game would expect $19$ losses, if you get unlucky with the first few bets, then even winning may not make up for a bad streak (e.g., if most of your wins occur once most of the wealth is gone). going broke with the smaller 1% stake is not possible in $38$ games.
                  The flip side is that the smaller stake will result in a much smaller profit on average, something like a $350$ fold increase with the large bet compared to $1.2$ increase with the small bet (i.e. you expect to have 24 dollars after 38 rounds with the small bet and 7000 dollars with the large bet).






                  share|cite|improve this answer









                  $endgroup$



                  I liked the answer given by Dave harris. just though I would come at the problem from a "low risk" perspective, rather than profit maximising



                  The random walk you are doing, assuming your fraction bet is $q$ and probability of winning $p=0.5$ has is given as
                  $$Y_t|Y_t-1=(1-q+3qX_t)Y_t-1$$
                  where $X_tsim Bernoulli(p)$. on average you have
                  $$E(Y_t|Y_t-1) = (1-q+3pq)Y_t-1$$
                  You can iteratively apply this to get
                  $$Y_t|Y_0=Y_0prod_j=1^t (1-q+3qX_t)$$
                  with expected value
                  $$E(Y_t|Y_0) = (1-q+3pq)^t Y_0$$
                  you can also express the amount at time $t$ as a function of a single random variable $Z_t=sum_j=1^t X_tsim Binomial(t,p)$, but noting that $Z_t$ is not independent from $Z_t-1$
                  $$Y_t|Y_0=Y_0 (1+2q)^Z_t(1-q)^t-Z_t$$



                  possible strategy



                  you could use this formula to determine a "low risk" value for $q$. Say assuming you wanted to ensure that after $k$ consecutive losses you still had half your original wealth. Then you set $q=1-2^-k^-1$



                  Taking the example $k=5$ means we set $q=0.129$, or with $k=15$ we set $q=0.045$.



                  Also, due to the recursive nature of the strategy, this risk is what you are taking every at every single bet. That is, at time $s$, by continuing to play you are ensuring that at time $k+s$ your wealth will be at least $0.5Y_s$



                  discussion



                  the above strategy does not depend on the pay off from winning, but rather about setting a boundary on losing. We can get the expected winnings by substituting in the value for $q$ we calculated, and at the time $k$ that was used with the risk in mind.



                  however, it is interesting to look at the median rather than expected pay off at time $t$, which can be found by assuming $median(Z_t)approx tp$.
                  $$Y_k|Y_0=Y_0 (1+2q)^tp(1-q)^t(1-p)$$
                  when $p=0.5$ the we have the ratio equal to $(1+q-2q^2)^0.5t$. This is maximised when $q=0.25$ and greater than $1$ when $q<0.5$



                  it is also interesting to calculate the chance you will be ahead at time $t$. to do this we need to determine the value $z$ such that
                  $$(1+2q)^z(1-q)^t-z>1$$
                  doing some rearranging we find that the proportion of wins should satisfy
                  $$fraczt>fraclog(1-q)log(1-q)-log(1+2q)$$
                  This can be plugged into a normal approximation (note: mean of $0.5$ and standard error of $frac0.5sqrtt$) as
                  $$Pr(textahead at time t)approxPhileft(sqrttfraclog(1+2q)+log(1-q)left[log(1+2q)-log(1-q)right]right)$$



                  which clearly shows the game has very good odds. the factor multiplying $sqrtt$ is minimised when $q=0$ (maximised value of $frac13$) and is monotonically decreasing as a function of $q$. so the "low risk" strategy is to bet a very small fraction of your wealth, and play a large number of times.



                  suppose we compare this with $q=frac13$ and $q=frac1100$. the factor for each case is $0.11$ and $0.32$. This means after $38$ games you would have around a 95% chance to be ahead with the small bet, compared to a 75% chance with the larger bet. Additionally, you also have a chance of going broke with the larger bet, assuming you had to round your stake to the nearest 5 cents or dollar. Starting with $20$ this could go $13.35, 8.90,5.95,3.95,2.65,1.75,1.15,0.75,0.50,0.35,0.25,0.15,0.1,0.05,0$.
                  This is a sequence of $14$ losses out of $38$, and given the game would expect $19$ losses, if you get unlucky with the first few bets, then even winning may not make up for a bad streak (e.g., if most of your wins occur once most of the wealth is gone). going broke with the smaller 1% stake is not possible in $38$ games.
                  The flip side is that the smaller stake will result in a much smaller profit on average, something like a $350$ fold increase with the large bet compared to $1.2$ increase with the small bet (i.e. you expect to have 24 dollars after 38 rounds with the small bet and 7000 dollars with the large bet).







                  share|cite|improve this answer












                  share|cite|improve this answer



                  share|cite|improve this answer










                  answered 1 hour ago









                  probabilityislogicprobabilityislogic

                  19.2k36385




                  19.2k36385




















                      ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor. Be nice, and check out our Code of Conduct.









                      draft saved

                      draft discarded


















                      ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor. Be nice, and check out our Code of Conduct.












                      ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor. Be nice, and check out our Code of Conduct.











                      ElectronicToothpick is a new contributor. Be nice, and check out our Code of Conduct.














                      Thanks for contributing an answer to Cross Validated!


                      • Please be sure to answer the question. Provide details and share your research!

                      But avoid


                      • Asking for help, clarification, or responding to other answers.

                      • Making statements based on opinion; back them up with references or personal experience.

                      Use MathJax to format equations. MathJax reference.


                      To learn more, see our tips on writing great answers.




                      draft saved


                      draft discarded














                      StackExchange.ready(
                      function ()
                      StackExchange.openid.initPostLogin('.new-post-login', 'https%3a%2f%2fstats.stackexchange.com%2fquestions%2f401480%2fthe-magic-money-tree-problem%23new-answer', 'question_page');

                      );

                      Post as a guest















                      Required, but never shown





















































                      Required, but never shown














                      Required, but never shown












                      Required, but never shown







                      Required, but never shown

































                      Required, but never shown














                      Required, but never shown












                      Required, but never shown







                      Required, but never shown







                      Popular posts from this blog

                      How to create a command for the “strange m” symbol in latex? Announcing the arrival of Valued Associate #679: Cesar Manara Planned maintenance scheduled April 23, 2019 at 23:30 UTC (7:30pm US/Eastern)How do you make your own symbol when Detexify fails?Writing bold small caps with mathpazo packageplus-minus symbol with parenthesis around the minus signGreek character in Beamer document titleHow to create dashed right arrow over symbol?Currency symbol: Turkish LiraDouble prec as a single symbol?Plus Sign Too Big; How to Call adfbullet?Is there a TeX macro for three-legged pi?How do I get my integral-like symbol to align like the integral?How to selectively substitute a letter with another symbol representing the same letterHow do I generate a less than symbol and vertical bar that are the same height?

                      Българска екзархия Съдържание История | Български екзарси | Вижте също | Външни препратки | Литература | Бележки | НавигацияУстав за управлението на българската екзархия. Цариград, 1870Слово на Ловешкия митрополит Иларион при откриването на Българския народен събор в Цариград на 23. II. 1870 г.Българската правда и гръцката кривда. От С. М. (= Софийски Мелетий). Цариград, 1872Предстоятели на Българската екзархияПодмененият ВеликденИнформационна агенция „Фокус“Димитър Ризов. Българите в техните исторически, етнографически и политически граници (Атлас съдържащ 40 карти). Berlin, Königliche Hoflithographie, Hof-Buch- und -Steindruckerei Wilhelm Greve, 1917Report of the International Commission to Inquire into the Causes and Conduct of the Balkan Wars

                      Чепеларе Съдържание География | История | Население | Спортни и природни забележителности | Културни и исторически обекти | Религии | Обществени институции | Известни личности | Редовни събития | Галерия | Източници | Литература | Външни препратки | Навигация41°43′23.99″ с. ш. 24°41′09.99″ и. д. / 41.723333° с. ш. 24.686111° и. д.*ЧепелареЧепеларски Linux fest 2002Начало на Зимен сезон 2005/06Национални хайдушки празници „Капитан Петко Войвода“Град ЧепелареЧепеларе – народният ски курортbgrod.orgwww.terranatura.hit.bgСправка за населението на гр. Исперих, общ. Исперих, обл. РазградМузей на родопския карстМузей на спорта и скитеЧепеларебългарскибългарскианглийскитукИстория на градаСки писти в ЧепелареВремето в ЧепелареРадио и телевизия в ЧепелареЧепеларе мами с родопски чар и добри пистиЕвтин туризъм и снежни атракции в ЧепелареМестоположениеИнформация и снимки от музея на родопския карст3D панорами от ЧепелареЧепелареррр